08 Feb 2016

Contra Krugman Episode 21, and Contra Cruise Ready for Booking!

Contra Krugman, Shameless Self-Promotion 6 Comments

Here’s the link to the latest episode, where Tom and I kinda sorta agree with Krugman’s reaction to Market Monetarists on the Fed and the Great Recession.

But perhaps more important, you can now reserve your spot on the 2016 Contra Cruise!!

08 Feb 2016

Notes on Black-Scholes (From 2003)

Financial Economics 7 Comments

The eclectic von Pepe asked me to dig these up… I haven’t reviewed them, but 2003 Bob knew this stuff better than 2016 Bob so let’s hope he didn’t screw up.

* * *

Notes on Black-Scholes
Robert P. Murphy
July 2003

A friend from the finance world asked me to review the original Black-Scholes paper on option pricing. I realized that my comments on the journal article might be of interest to others, and so I am preparing these notes for public consumption. Let me confess at the outset that I am an expert in neither finance nor statistics. (Please drop me an email if you think there’s an error below.) Nonetheless, I hope to shed at least some light on what Black and Scholes do in this seminal work.

I will go through the paper, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” published in the Journal of Political Economy. (I don’t have an exact citation handy at the moment.) These notes will make more sense if you have a copy of the paper yourself.

The Problem

An option is “a security giving the right [but not the obligation] to buy or sell an asset, subject to certain conditions, within a specified period of time” (637). The most straightforward example is a call option, which gives its owner the right (but not the obligation) to buy a share of stock at a certain price (called the “strike price”), in a specified time interval.

The problem is, how much should these options be worth? If a share of IBM stock currently sells for $10, how much should I pay for an option that gives me the right to buy a share of IBM for $15 anytime in the next 12 months? How much should I pay for the option if the strike price is $8?

The Black-Scholes formula gives us a rational procedure for computing the “true value” of options. The problem is not so much in predicting what options will actually sell for on the market; the problem is to define what the “rational” speculator will do on the market. When it comes to regular consumer goods, this problem doesn’t arise: People pay more for steak than hamburger because they enjoy steak more than hamburger. But when it comes to options, it is not clear how much people should value such complicated assets. This is where the Black-Scholes formula comes in.

Abstract

We can first turn to the article abstract, to see how Black and Scholes themselves viewed their contribution:

If options are correctly priced in the market, it should not be possible to make sure profits by creating portfolios of long and short positions in options and their underlying stocks. Using this principle, a theoretical valuation formula for options is derived.

Here Black-Scholes rely on the no-arbitrage condition, which has proved so useful in formal economics. To give some background: In mathematical economics, an equilibrium set of prices is defined as one in which all market participants, given their endowments of resources and the market prices, formulate plans (of buying and selling decisions) that (a) maximize the utility of each agent and (b) are all compatible with each other. For example, if the equilibrium price of apples is $2/pound, then people must collectively desire to sell X apples at this price, and people must collectively desire to buy X apples at this price.

In this framework, a necessary condition for equilibrium is that the price system contains no arbitrage or pure profit opportunities. If this were not the case, then individual agents would attempt to earn an infinite amount of money by exploiting the price differentials; since this is impossible, the prices would have to quickly adjust to eliminate the arbitraging action. But if the prices must change, that means the original set of prices (which contained the pure profit opportunity) must not have been an equilibrium one.

Returning to Black-Scholes, we see that they are employing this technique to determine how options “should” be priced. Black-Scholes are adopting the rather modest position that a necessary condition of option prices is that they do not allow for arbitrage in the securities market.

Before proceeding, consider an analogy with production. Suppose oranges are selling in Florida at $2 per pound, and that the transportation costs to ship them to New York are ten cents per pound. If oranges sell in New York at more than $2.10 per pound, then a merchant can engage in (almost) riskless arbitrage by buying the oranges in Florida and selling them in New York. From an economic point of view, the Florida-oranges-plus-transportation is “equivalent” to New-York-oranges, and so the market price of both “portfolios” must be the same in equilibrium. When the prices of the two portfolios diverge, we would say that the oranges are incorrectly priced.

With this approach, we can say that an option is “underpriced” if its buyer is assured of pure (riskless) profits, and we can say that an option is “overpriced” if its seller is assured of the same. By the process of elimination, if an option is neither underpriced nor overpriced, we say it is correctly priced.

How can someone make sure profits through securities transactions? Well, notice that certain portfolios are “equivalent” from a financial point of view. For example:

call (strike price $x) + risk-free bond ($x face) = stock (selling at $x) + put (s.p. $x)

Regardless of the movement in the price of the stock, both portfolios will always give the same payoff at expiration. If the price S remains at $x, then the put and call options are worthless at expiration, and the bond pays (at time of expiration) $x while the stock can be sold for $x. If the price of the stock goes above the strike, then at expiration the call is worth S-x, while the put is worthless. Thus the left-hand portfolio above is worth (S-x)+x, while the right-hand portfolio is worth the share price of the stock, S. Finally, if the price of the stock goes below the strike, then at expiration the call is worthless while the put is worth x-S. Thus the left-hand portfolio is worth x while the right-hand portfolio is worth S+(x-S).

Because these two portfolios have the same payoff (at expiration), regardless of what happens to the price of the underlying stock, no-arbitrage requires that the price (at any time prior to expiration) of both portfolios be the same. If the price of one of the portfolios, say the left-hand one, were lower than the other, then a speculator could earn a “riskless” profit by buying the left-hand portfolio and selling the right-hand one.

For example, suppose that a share of stock XYZ sells for $100, and that calls and puts (with strike price $100) sell for $10 and $5, respectively. That means the right-hand portfolio above costs $105. Now if a risk-free bond paying $100 at the time of expiration currently sells for anything less than $95, a speculator can earn a pure profit by buying the left-hand portfolio and selling the right-hand one. (This will happen—i.e. the risk-free bond with face value of $100 will sell for under $95—whenever the relevant interest rate is higher than roughly 5.3%.)

In the example above, all I’ve done is show that the prices of puts, calls, and stocks must obey a certain relationship, given an interest rate. This alone doesn’t tell us how to actually price an option. (Further restrictions are described at this website.) Nonetheless, my example does illustrate the approach of Black-Scholes. A correctly priced option can withstand any type of portfolio selection, not just the specific two that I described above.

Introduction

Black-Scholes specifically state their goal later at the end of their Introduction: “[I]n equilibrium, the expected return on such a hedged position must be equal to the return on a riskless asset. What we show below is that this equilibrium condition can be used to derive a theoretical valuation formula.” (p. 640)

By “hedged position” they are referring to a portfolio that gives a guaranteed return, regardless of the movement of the stock price. For example, suppose an investor buys a share of stock XYZ, buys a (European) put, and sells a (European) call, with strike prices of $100 each, which can only be exercised in twelve months’ time. The resulting portfolio is a hedged position, guaranteeing $100 in twelve months. If the price of XYZ turns out to be $100, then the options expire worthless and the investor can sell the stock. If the price is higher than $100, then the put is worthless, but the sold call will be exercised—the investor will have to surrender his share for only $100. Finally, if the price is lower than $100, then the call will not be exercised, and the investor can use his put to sell his share for $100.

Keep in mind, though, that this guaranteed return can only be enjoyed in one year. During that time, whatever funds the investor originally spent on the portfolio will remain tied up (when they could have been earning interest on a risk-free bond). In the example above, suppose the stock initially sells for $90, while the put sells for $10 and the call sells for $5. In that case, the investor would need to invest $95 today in order to receive $100 (guaranteed) in twelve months. This can only be an equilibrium outcome if the rate of return on risk-free bonds for twelve months is also 5.26% (approximately).

Assumptions

The final thing I will do in these notes is elaborate on one of the Black-Scholes assumptions. (The other assumptions are fairly self-explanatory.) This is the second assumption, which states, “b) The stock price follows a random walk in continuous time…”

A random walk model of stock prices means that, at any time t, the expected value of the stock at any time t+∆ is simply its current price. This doesn’t mean that people “expect” that the price of the stock will actually remain constant. Rather, it means that the “best guess” is the current price, because there is just as much chance for the price to go up as for it to go down.

The motivation for this assumption is that markets are assumed to be efficient. Whatever information individual traders possess about the company or the economy in general, is assumed to have already worked its way into all current share prices.

If this is one’s view of the economy, then it would be silly to argue that, “You should buy shares in Oscar Mayer right before the 4th of July, because hot dog sales will go through the roof.” Presumably, enough people already know this fact, and so the price of Oscar Mayer stock will already take this consideration fully into account. Absent any insider information, then, one should expect the price of Oscar Mayer to be just as likely to go down on July 4th as to go up. (Of course, the price of the stock is higher than it would have been had the government previously announced a cancellation of the holiday, but the point is that the price is at its higher level all along; it doesn’t jump up to the high level on the day of the holiday itself.)

When modeling stock prices, then, Black-Scholes assumes that the change in levels has a mathematical expectation of 0, with a certain variance and other properties that allow for tractable analysis.

07 Feb 2016

Portrait of the Bible Neophyte as a Young Man

Religious 28 Comments

Especially for those of you who are believers, I strongly encourage you to get into a systematic study of the Bible. This should include not only reading the whole thing cover to cover (you might take more than a year to do it), but also supplementing your personal reading with expert commentary. For example, once you get used to his style, you might really enjoy Vernon McGee. I travel a lot back and forth from Lubbock to Houston, and now the 9 hour trip zips by because I load up my iPod with McGee’s commentary.

To give an example of how much my own understanding of the God of the Bible has changed, let me relate a personal anecdote. Back when I was in grad school, but before I had gone through the experiences that rescued me from atheism, I wrote an article for LewRockwell.com in which I defended the website from someone who had launched a quite patronizing attack.

So the person attacking LRC had written something like, “Those whiny libertarians are banging their high chairs and yelling that they think taxes are TOO HIGH. God bless ’em.” (That’s a paraphrase.)

Now you must understand, I was an angry young man at the time, and this guy’s column really set me off. So in response to his “God bless ’em” line, I wrote something like, “The people at LRC would never ask their God to fight their battles for them.”

What I was trying to do was contrast the serious people who were warning about civil liberties and the warfare state, with the smart aleck Republican thinking we were babies and needed to defer to the adults in the room who knew the real issue was the payroll tax rate.

But now when I think back to that episode, it’s funny to me just how ignorant I was of the Old Testament–even though I had nominally read a lot of it when I was younger. In fact, the children of Israel were SUPPOSED to let their God fight their battles for them. They got into trouble whenever they DIDN’T rely on God, and instead tried to solve their problems through their own strength or alliances with pagan kings.

In conclusion, even if you are a believer and even if you have kinda sorta read the Bible cover to cover once in your life, I strongly encourage you to begin a systematic study with an expert commentator. You will begin to see themes and–if your experience is like mine–you will no longer see such a huge contrast between the super nice guy Jesus and that mean God of the Old Testament. Instead the whole book will become a seamless tale of God’s faithfulness in the face of His fickle children, who must ultimately be saved not because they earned it but because of His unmerited gift. Even the “heroes” of the Old Testament are often scoundrels, and their only admirable trait is that they occasionally have amazing faith that God will achieve mighty things through them.

05 Feb 2016

Am I Just a Permabear?

Efficient Markets Hypothesis, Federal Reserve, Financial Economics 94 Comments

In the comments of this post, Gene Callahan doesn’t shirk his duty of constantly assuming I started reading financial economics last Tuesday:

But Bob, weren’t you predicting market disaster when the Dow was at 6000? (I was buying at that point, fwiw.) Weren’t you predicting it through the whole rise of the last seven years?

If I predicted the death of David Bowie every day for the last 7 years, do I get to crow this month when he actually dies?

If the Dow gets back down to 15,000 it is buy time again. Do you want to write a derivative contract on whatever position I take so you can short my position?

No, I don’t think I was predicting a stock market crash when the markets bottomed out in March 2009. I’m not betting my life on that, but I don’t remember doing that. I think instead what happened is that I was adamantly against the Fed’s policies from the fall of 2008 onward (actually from the fall of 2007 onward…), and then when various mockers pointed at the booming stock market as proof that guys like me were idiots, at that point I started saying the boom in equities was built on quicksand. However, if Gene can find me saying the stock market was overvalued in March 2009, I will note it here as a correction.

Now, the broader issue is that I don’t think I’m grasping at straws, or merely chanting “Disaster looms!” when I say that the stock market (I normally use S&P500 but below I use the DJIA for Gene) has been driven by the Fed:

I want to be clear that Austrian theory per se doesn’t posit a mechanical connection between the stock market and the Fed’s balance sheet. I have been using that graphical device to get people to see that there is an obvious connection if you are willing to use your eyes.

Now if the connection holds–which it might not, for example if everyone suddenly thought I was a genius then the market would tank instantly–then for the Dow to go back to 15,000, the monetary base would be “only” $3.2 trillion, still 4x the height it was eight years ago.

Does anyone think that is sustainable? Maybe that’s what is throwing people here. I am assuming throughout this discussion that the Fed eventually has to let its balance sheet (as a share of GDP if you prefer) go back to pre-crisis levels. That was what Bernanke said in the beginning when he unleashed this genie.

Beyond that, I am really puzzled by how many generally free market economists (not saying anarcho-capitalists but people who generally respect markets absent a compelling reason otherwise) think that trillion dollar deficits, massive government expansion in health care and health insurance, regulations on power plants and potential big carbon tax in the wings, and the list of horrible presidential candidates all lead to a record breaking stock market. When Krugman celebrates the Obama Boom that somewhat makes sense, because he thinks what this economy needs is more government. But it baffles me how many generally free-market economists think the booming stock market of the last few years makes perfect sense.

Here’s the long term picture. I don’t see why people warning that the market is poised for a big drop are being treated like kindergartners.

DJIA long term

05 Feb 2016

IER Analysis of Obama’s Proposed $10 per Barrel Tax on Oil

All Posts 2 Comments

Here.

05 Feb 2016

Treasury Yield Curve Over the Last Year

Federal Reserve, Scott Sumner 1 Comment

This might be useful to some of you:

It’s obvious in the above that the Fed action has raised very short term rates while bringing down longer rates. (To explain some of the movements earlier, remember that markets thought the Fed was first going to raise the fed funds target in September, and then it backed off when things went nuts in the financial markets in August after the China currency move.)

Fortunately Scott clarified in the comments of the last post that it was only a subset of Austrians who had simplistic views about short- and long-term interest rates. As you may recall, recently I invoked the common (but not perfect) pattern of a textbook Fed tightening leading to (a) rising short rates and (b) stable or even falling long rates to explain why an inverted yield curve “predicts” recessions, and how that flows naturally from textbook Austrian business cycle theory.

P.S. The Internet is awful at communicating body language, tone of voice, etc. Let me once again state that the reason I go after both Krugman and Sumner is that they are very intelligent and glib cheerleaders of policy proposals that I think are terrible. As David Beckworth has gained more traction I put him in the crosshairs too. If I try to blow you up on my blog, it’s because I respect your power.

05 Feb 2016

The Fed’s Magic Trick Won’t Work

Federal Reserve, Shameless Self-Promotion 36 Comments

05 Feb 2016

Hit and Run on Sumner

Federal Reserve, Scott Sumner 22 Comments

We have a super duper awesome conference this weekend here at the Free Market Institute, so I have to be brief. Let me first motivate this post by issuing the following statement, to which I want you to react:

*** Ten-year bond yields have plummeted to 1.83%, from about 2.2% when the Fed “raised” interest rates in December. I hope all the Market Monetarists whining about the Fed’s “target rate being above the natural rate” are pleased to have gotten your way. ***

Let that sink in for a moment. I’m guessing any Market Monetarist fan reading this post will now be sure–in case there was any doubt before–that I am either (a) an idiot, (b) an intellectually dishonest scoundrel, or (c) both. If you think about the above statement, you’ll realize that there are at least three things wrong/unfair about it, and that I would have no business leveling that against Market Monetarists.

The reason I bring this up is that in reality, here is what Scott Sumner recently wrote on his blog:

“Or how about 10-year bond yields plummeting to 1.83%, from about 2.2% when they “raised” interest rates in December. I hope all you Austrians who whined about “artificially low rates” being set by the Fed are pleased to have gotten your way.”

Now on to something far more substantive. Look at how Scott–one of the world’s leading free market experts on monetary policy–thinks about this stuff: “In a better world the risk of recession and the risk of the economy overheating would always be evenly balanced. And I mean always, every single day of the year.”

And there you have it. When people in the comments refer to Scott as a Keynesian, this is what they mean. This is straight up crude demand management. We don’t need to know about relative prices or capital structure. There is a tradeoff between unemployment and (price) inflation and it’s the Fed’s job to turn the dial one way or the other to coast through the sweet spot.

Against that perspective, consider Hayek from his Nobel address:

The theory which has been guiding monetary and financial policy during the last thirty years, and which I contend is largely the product of such a mistaken conception of the proper scientific procedure, consists in the assertion that there exists a simple positive correlation between total employment and the size of the aggregate demand for goods and services; it leads to the belief that we can permanently assure full employment by maintaining total money expenditure at an appropriate level. Among the various theories advanced to account for extensive unemployment, this is probably the only one in support of which strong quantitative evidence can be adduced. I nevertheless regard it as fundamentally false, and to act upon it, as we now experience, as very harmful.

P.S. I realize Scott was just venting on this particular blog post, such that he devolved into jokes about the NBA. Take my remarks above in the same light-hearted spirit.